Proofs of this now commonsensical truth of socialism’s historical
failure come from many quarters. The first and most obvious proof that these
regimes led to economic, social and political bankruptcy is simply that they
fell - sometimes, like in Romania, following widespread popular contestation. Socialist
state companies were notoriously inefficient, technologically backward, and
produced insufficient capital and consumer goods, leading to ‘economies of
shortage’ in the former soviet space. Besides, these regimes were also
inherently violent, resting on the partial interest of the proletariat and its
dictatorship, manifested in the violent suppression and persecution of members
of other social classes (bourgeoisie, but also intellectuals and peasants). Moreover,
far from abolishing social inequalities through class struggle, socialist
regimes produced their own inequalities, namely between the high party and
state nomenklatura, benefitting from special access to goods and outside
mobility, and normal citizens, lacking in both basic goods and freedom of
movement. Finally, are these regimes not proven wrong by the irrepressible urge
their populations displayed towards participating in the ‘Western’ consumer
paradise? Did they not just long to dump socialism and embrace capitalism in
order to eat more bananas, chewing gum and Coca Cola?
Good as they may be as backdrop for the heroic bildungsroman of
liberated Eastern Europeans, these depictions serve more to justify what has
come after ‘really existing socialism’ than to really attend to its
understanding. At least part of the events or processes invoked by these assertions
occurred or were evaluated post-factum when socialist regimes were no more: the
fall of socialism itself, the consumerist urge in post-socialist CEE, the
post-socialist re-evaluation as trauma of the socialist experience of
intellectuals and members of the old bourgeoisie, the post-socialist devaluation
of state companies and their subsequent bankruptcy, etc. Well, well, that may
be so, but what? Does it matter to understand ‘really existing socialism’ now
that it is irremediably gone and nobody decent seems to seriously envisage
going back to it? What, one could wonder, would this socialism be good for
anything else than serve as a reservoir of oddities for contemporary screen dramas
and comedies?
By arguing that really existing socialism is still ‘good to think with’,
I am not saying that all was good with it, or that it was paradise on earth.
But I do propose that imagining ways to overcome capitalism cannot do without
understanding the intricacies of this particular, very real brand of socialism.
Making really existing socialism a gross, but highly transparent version of
hell helped to deflate critiques of capitalism and impose its neoliberal
version to an unprecedented scale after 1989. It also helped even in recent,
and more contesting times, when anti-globalisation movements were all too often
accused of ‘offering no viable alternative’. This is, of course, because voices
advocating for alternatives to capitalism were not deemed ‘viable’ by
mainstream media, but also because many left-wing thinkers and activists were
reluctant to look in a constructive manner at really existing socialisms. This
reluctance contributed to legitimise, by silence, the tight symbolic link that
came to be made after 1989 between the capitalist paradise and the socialist
hell. The re-evaluation of really existing capitalism seems therefore to be
difficult without a scrupulous, but honest re-evaluation of really existing
socialism.
Granted, the visibility and acceptability of alternatives seem to be
connected more to power relations than to actual knowledge. Really existing
socialism was, in the geo-political power game of the Cold War, an alternative
as viable as its existence in a dozen countries, among several million people
and across several million square kilometres can get. But its threat went
beyond population and territorial coverage or the military power of the URSSR
into offering a living example of how societies could be organized around
collective ownership. So maybe knowledge of how this example worked and what it
meant for those who lived through it could also be useful in imagining other,
future alternatives to contemporary capitalism?
I will bring here a few elements on how we could start to think anew of
really existing socialism, mostly by trying to unpack some of the current
oppositions used in thinking about the socialist-capitalist dyad. In order to
make the story more readable, I will use the term ‘socialism’ as a shortcut for
‘really existing socialism’. I will also concentrate on CEE socialism and
particularly on Romanian socialism, as these are the cases that I know best. I
will start by addressing in the first part some of the oppositions used in
thinking about how socialist economies were organised. The second part will
deal with some of the premises used in thinking about the social consequences
of these economies.
Static vs. dynamic, closed vs. open economies
Most of the times that socialism is invoked these days by journalists,
politicians and even academics, it is done so in a totalizing, unifying way. ‘Socialism’
was bad, and did a list of bad things that contemporary market, capitalist
economies would not do (see a summary of such a list above in the second
paragraph). But was there one, the same and only socialism that existed, so
that we could say that one, the same and only socialism did all the bad things?
The first fallacy in this kind of approach is to think that, while
capitalism is inherently dynamic, socialism, by contrast, was a static entity
equal to itself during the almost half a century of its existence in Central
and Eastern Europe. Socialism seems thus to have crystalized into an ice bloc
that has not melted away even almost half a century after its official demise:
even now, many analysts explain post-socialist transformations in terms of
‘socialist legacies’ rather than the neo-liberal order instituted after 1989.
By contrast, 24 years into the socialist period it was agreed that socialism
was solidly instituted with few voices, even among socialist apparatchiks,
invoking ‘bourgeois legacies’.
Socialism, like capitalism, has, however, a history. It passed from the
political repression and economic restructuring of the late 1940s and 1950s, to
the period of industrialization, growth and opening of the 1960s and 1970s, plunging
afterwards into crisis during the 1980s. ‘Socialism’ is therefore not equal to
itself, but had several periods that were quite distinctive on a macroeconomic
level and on the level of its population’s daily life. Social mobility, for
example, passed from very high levels in the first period to more modest ones
in the second, finally stabilizing in the third, while consumer goods shortages
went from very high levels immediately after the second World War, to rather
low ones in the 1960s and 1970s, only to increase again during the 80s .
Ok, its critics would say, maybe socialism changed over time, but it
still inherently produced some bad things that capitalist societies are
shielded from. And here we have the second fallacy - that of thinking that
socialism developed like cucumbers in a greenhouse in isolation from any
outside forces. As the saying goes, socialism led to closed economies, whereas
capitalism to open ones. Socialist countries were not, however, isolated in a
tightly knit, autarchic bloc, but were enmeshed in the larger world economy. Competition
and antagonism, but also cooperation between the two blocs played a role in
various proportions during the half a century of socialist experiments in the
East. Anti-bourgeois political persecution in the East at the end of the 1940s
and beginning of the 1950s was mirrored by anti-communist persecution in the
USA during the same period. Political surveillance in the East during the 80s
was mirrored by political surveillance in the West during the same period.
Most importantly, most CEE countries became members of the IMF at the
beginning of the 1970s and started to indebt themselves in order to buy
technology and continue industrialisation. This also made them particularly
vulnerable, in terms of energy and financing costs, to the world crises of 1973
and 1982. Ironically, de-modernisation in Romania during the 1980s, a result of
its president’s resolution to pay off the country’s international debt, was paralleled
in the same period by de-industrialisation in the West. East and West, lost
generations came to the fore. Only that in the East, much more was to be lost
after socialism was gone.
Plan vs. Market
One of the most current accusations against socialism is that it relied
on the Plan rather than the Market to regulate its economy and allocate
resources in society. Planning, as the story goes, led to an irrational
allocation of resources, as it resulted in ‘soft budget constraints’, hoarding
by state company managers to prevent supply shortages, overstating of their
companies’ input needs, and finally a generalised ‘economy of shortage’. The
market in capitalist economies allows, by contrast, a rational allocation of
resources because it provides hard budget constraints, clear sanctions to those
who overestimate their supply and demand needs, incentives for efficiency and
finally an abundance of goods.
The plan and the market have not been, however, so neatly distributed on
the two sides of the socialist/capitalist divide. Socialist economies generated
important segments of informal and black market exchanges to smooth out
scarcity in the formal sector of their economies. On the other side, planning
was adopted by western countries as a tool to attend to the larger involvement
of the state in their economies and societies after the Second World War. Most
ironically, planning rose to new heights during the last decades of neoliberal
capitalism. The reconfiguration of the public sector through "new public
management" imported from the private sector indicates that the use of the
market as a principle of regulation (which was what NPM was all about) actually
translated into the implementation of a Plan involving objectives, indicators,
competitive benchmarking, rankings and classifications. Admittedly, unlike the socialist
Plan, the managerial Plan aims to reduce the size and importance of public
institutions and to change their mode of operation by giving more space to the
private sector. But, under this plan, while public institutions are submitted
to the constraints of cost-benefit calculations, their partners in the private
sector are provided with a guaranteed and risk-free outlet in the public sector.
So much so for the hard budget constraints of the capitalist private sector...
But soft budget constraints in capitalist
economies, including the advanced ones, affect more than just private companies
in public-private partnerships. Many sectors in western economies, such as private
research and development in the areas of defence and pharmaceuticals, or, in
the USA, agriculture and information and communication technologies, receive
strong state support and thus benefit from significantly lower budget
constraints than their non-western competitors. And some business practices
across sectors also serve the same purpose. Budget constraints can be manipulated,
for example, by "transfer pricing" through which TNC move their
profits to countries with lower tax rates, or by price manipulations by some
large companies through input stocking or product dumping. Ironically, easy
targets of neo-liberal demands to end state support, it is now post-socialist state
enterprises and public sector units around the world which embody the ideal of
the capitalist company disciplined by strong budget and demand constraints.
[For Part II of this essay click here.]
Sabina Stan is Lecturer in Anthropology and Sociology at Dublin City University, Ireland, and currently a fellow at the Centre for Advanced Study at the Norwegian Academy of Science and Letters.
[For Part II of this essay click here.]
Sabina Stan is Lecturer in Anthropology and Sociology at Dublin City University, Ireland, and currently a fellow at the Centre for Advanced Study at the Norwegian Academy of Science and Letters.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Comments welcome!