Despite the prolonged global economic
crisis since 2007/2008, neo-liberal economic thought and practice continue to
reign supreme. In his important book Capitalist Globalization: Consequences, Resistance and Alternatives (Monthly Review
Press, 2013), Martin Hart-Landsberg makes a number of key interventions
unravelling the myth of neo-liberalism as well as the dynamics underlying
capitalist accumulation.
Second, Hart-Landsberg makes clear why
the push for free trade agreements (FTAs) has become so prominent. In order to
ensure that cross-border production networks function smoothly, the unhindered
flow of parts and components is an absolutely essential precondition. ‘All
together, 119 FTAs were negotiated in the Asia-Pacific region between 2002 and
2006. During the period, China negotiated or proposed FTAs with 28 different
countries. By comparison, the total was 21 for the European Union and 10 for
the United States’ (P.30). The large number of FTAs by China, however, does not
support ideas of a rising economic giant. Rather, it is China’s cheap labour
that make it an ideal assembly platform of pre-fabricated parts for export to
North America and Europe. In fact, whole East Asia is dependent on these export
locations. ‘Since the region’s trade activity largely involves an intraregional
trade of parts and components culminating in China-based exports aimed
primarily at the United States and the European Union, the reality is that Asia
has become ever more tightly integrated and dependent on exporting to developed
capitalist markets, especially the United States’ (P.36). In other words,
instead of economic powerhouse, China turns out to be in a highly fragile position
in the global economy.
While economic growth measured in national GDP levels may look impressive, when growth is calculated in terms of share in value-added, the picture changes drastically. Hart-Landsberg draws convincingly on Mexico, which had embarked on such a growth strategy years earlier than China. ‘Between 1980 and 1997 Mexico’s share in world manufactured exports rose tenfold, while its share in world manufacturing value added fell by more than one-third, and its share in world income (at current dollars) [fell] by about 13 percent’ (PP.85-6). The main profit is made by large Western TNCs, which draw on cheap labour in China and other locations, be it directly, be it via sub-contractors such as the case of Apple with Foxconn in China. As John Smith illustrates, ‘Hon Hai [Foxconn] made $2.4 billion in profits in 2010, or $2,400 per employee, compared to $263,000 in profits reaped by Apple for each of its 63,000 employees (43,000 of whom are in the United States)’ (Smith 2012).
While economic growth measured in national GDP levels may look impressive, when growth is calculated in terms of share in value-added, the picture changes drastically. Hart-Landsberg draws convincingly on Mexico, which had embarked on such a growth strategy years earlier than China. ‘Between 1980 and 1997 Mexico’s share in world manufactured exports rose tenfold, while its share in world manufacturing value added fell by more than one-third, and its share in world income (at current dollars) [fell] by about 13 percent’ (PP.85-6). The main profit is made by large Western TNCs, which draw on cheap labour in China and other locations, be it directly, be it via sub-contractors such as the case of Apple with Foxconn in China. As John Smith illustrates, ‘Hon Hai [Foxconn] made $2.4 billion in profits in 2010, or $2,400 per employee, compared to $263,000 in profits reaped by Apple for each of its 63,000 employees (43,000 of whom are in the United States)’ (Smith 2012).
Equally important is the changing nature
of FTAs. Since the end of the GATT Uruguay Round in 1994, the free trade agenda
has been expanded from a focus on lowering tariffs to new areas including
intellectual property rights, trade in services and trade related investment
measures (Bieler, Hilary and Lindberg 2014: 3-5). The expanded free trade
agenda, importantly, also includes state-investor enforcement mechanisms,
undermining state sovereignty vis-à-vis TNCs further. Hart-Landsberg
illustrates this well in relation to the US – South Korea FTA and concludes ‘no
wonder that government and business leaders prefer to call the KORUS FTA a free
trade agreement and to concentrate public attention on tariff issues. If the
full requirements of this and other agreements were popularly known, people
might better understand why they face ever worsening options. They would see
that their situation is primarily the result of well applied class power rather
than impersonal “market forces”. And they would better appreciate the need to
organize in their own defense’ (P.118). In short, talking about free trade has
increasingly become a smoke-screen for more drastic restructuring measures.
The last point leads into Hard-Landsberg’s
fourth major contribution. He demonstrates clearly that state-centric
approaches are increasingly obsolete. As he states early on, ‘the fact that a
diverse group of states continue to pursue policies that significantly limit
their own authority over economic activity highlights the existence of a common
class interest shared by transnational capital, one that transcends national
and competitive differences’ (P.26). In short, when analysing capitalist
exploitation and resistance, it is not state rivalry and co-operation, which
has to be at the core of investigation, but class struggle. ‘This reality
highlights the critical importance of studying capitalist dynamics from a class
rather than nation-state perspective’ (P.62).
Photo by Greenpeace Switzerland |
Importantly, where other academics stop
in their analysis of what is going on, Hart-Landsberg continues and looks for
potential alternatives and social class forces, who could support them.
Clearly, resistance by trade unions is not automatic. When assessing the
position of US unions vis-à-vis the FTA with South Korea, Hart-Landsberg
concludes that ‘unfortunately, the demand for “review and renegotiate” suggests
that there is a basic core to the agreement that is acceptable. The implication
is that contemporary capitalist accumulation dynamics provide an acceptable
framework for structuring a fair, equitable, and responsive relationship
between the two countries’ (P.126). Successful resistance requires broader
alliances with a perspective beyond the workplace, Hart-Landsberg concludes. ‘We
need to develop a strategic focus that can help us build movements for change
that embrace the principles of equality, democracy, and solidarity in both
practice and vision’ (P.134).
Photo by little shiva |
If there is one criticism I have to
make, then it is the missing conclusion. It would have been useful, if
Hart-Landsberg had summed up the results of his investigation and deliberated
about the implications for the future. Nonetheless, this is a hugely impressive
book, which I highly recommend for reading to all those academics and activists
alike, wanting to contribute to resistance against capitalist exploitation. Considering
current negotiations of a Trans-Pacific
Partnership Agreement (TPPA), a US-EU Transatlantic Trade and Investment
Partnership (TTIP) as well as a Trade in Services Agreement (TISA), this book
will remain essential reading for some time.
References:
Bieler, Andreas, John Hilary and Ingemar
Lindberg (2014) ‘Trade Unions, “Free Trade” and the Problem of Transnational
Solidarity: An Introduction’, Globalizations,Vol.11/1: 1-9.
Smith,
John (2012) ‘The GDP Illusion: Value Added versus Value Capture’, Monthly Review, Vol.64/3; available at http://monthlyreview.org/2012/07/01/the-gdp-illusion,
accessed 08/11/2013.
10 August 2014
Prof. Andreas Bieler
Professor of Political Economy
University of Nottingham/UK
Personal website: http://andreasbieler.net
10 August 2014
No comments:
Post a Comment
Comments welcome!