While Prime
Minister Boris Johnson intends to turn the current general elections into a
contest over Brexit, it is Jeremy Corbyn’s Labour Party, which offers a real political
alternative including wide-ranging plans for renationalizing key services such
as the railways, energy, postal services and water. In this blog post, I
discuss the lessons to be learned from struggles over public water across Europe.
Supporters of privatising public services argue that thanks
to the competitive pressures of the ‘free market’ four benign consequences
would result: (1) the production of services becomes more efficient; (2) the
quality of the services is improved; (3) the cost of services for the consumer
is reduced; and (4) companies providing these services can still make a profit.
The private provision of water too, they argue, is subject to the same
beneficial market pressures.
The reality, however, looks rather different. Water
privatisation has generally resulted in insufficient investment into
infrastructure, soaring consumer tariffs, lower levels of efficiency, poor
service quality and ‘the failure of private water corporations to contribute
investment finance’ (Lobina 2014: 10). Only one of the four envisaged consequences has actually occurred due
to privatisation: companies’ ability to make large amounts of profit. As Aditya
Chakrabortty reported in the Guardian, between 2007 and 2012 there was only one
year in which the consortium of shareholders of Thames Water in the UK took out
less money of the company than it had made in post-tax profits, thereby
doubling the company’s debt to £7.8 billion (Chakrabortty 2014).
These corporate
profits have come at the expense of consumers, who have seen their water bills
increase drastically. In the Italian region of Tuscany, for example,
privatisations in the late 1990s, early 2000s resulted in an average increase
in water charges of 24 per cent. In some communities, the increase was even a
staggering 120 per cent. In the UK too,
corporate profits have been financed by users. Even though operation costs have
remained the same, water bills have increased by 50 per cent over the last two
decades.
In short, water privatisation is not about how to
provide best water. The main purpose is to generate private profits! Rather
than being about efficiency and universal access of water, this discourse of
superior private services facilitates a redistribution of income from people to
private companies.
Yet, privatisation
is neither inevitable nor irreversible. In Greece, despite the pressures of the
Eurozone crisis, to date broad alliances of trade unions and social movements
have successfully defended the highly profitable and efficient public water
companies in Athens and Thessaloniki against privatisation. When the Irish government
wanted to introduce additional water charges in 2014, large demonstrations, a widespread
non-payment campaign and the physical blocking of the installation of water
meters forced the government to withdraw its plans in 2016.
Moreover,
re-municipalisation pays off, indicating where the real savings may lie. In
2010, when water had been taken back into public hands in Paris, the new water
provider ensured savings of about €35 million. Water tariffs were reduced by 8
per cent as a result.
The forthcoming
elections offer English citizens the opportunity to end water privatisation and
follow examples set elsewhere. Labour does not simply intend returning to the
past. Together with the think tank We Own It, it has developed plans towards the democratisation of these public,
regional companies working towards an affordable, sustainable and efficient
water provision for everyone (see When We Own
It).
Andreas Bieler
Professor of Political Economy
University of Nottingham/UK
Andreas Bieler
University of Nottingham/UK
No comments:
Post a Comment
Comments welcome!