With all of the
kerfuffle in the UK academic world about open access journals−meaning without
legal or financial barriers to gain access to publically-funded academic work−and
the fudge underway to resolve this in the interests of publishers, Adam David Morton and I are delighted to
announce a new article of ours now available in the Journal of AustralianPolitical Economy (JAPE). This journal publishes peer-reviewed articles
and is fully open access. The latest issue includes the annual E. L.
Wheelwright Lecture by Susan George, articles on urban political economy, and
our joint article on recasting contemporary geopolitics, territorial processes
of capitalist accumulation, and spaces of imperialist rivalry. Our article is
entitled ‘The will-o’-the-wisp of the transnational state’ and can be freely
accessed here.
Our argument is
that while the role of the state in the global political economy, or the
relationship between the inter-state system and globalisation, has been the
focus of scholarly debate for some time, mainstream debates have run out of
steam. On one hand, neo-realists argue that the inter-state system has not
changed fundamentally and states remain the only significant actors. On the
other hand, liberals speak about a transformed system within which the
relevance of states is on the retreat in light of the juggernaut of
globalisation. Instead, we shift our attention by critically engaging with a series
of historical materialist contributions to the debate on geopolitics and global
capitalism. We argue that by drawing on the work of Antonio Gramsci and Nicos
Poulantzas it is possible to focus on the way the interests of transnational
capital have become internalised in various forms of state to, thus, comprehend
the internal relationship between global capitalism and the inter-state system
but without succumbing to the notion that a ‘transnational state’ is emerging
as a result.
The main focus
from a historical materialist stance is on why the state and the market, the
political and the economic, appear as two separate entities under capitalism. Some
Marxists, such as Werner
Bonefeld or Peter
Burnham, usefully explain the historical specificity of capitalism through
an analysis of the underlying social relations of production. In a capitalist
productive system based on wage labour and the private ownership of the means
of production, the extraction of surplus value is not directly politically
enforced, but the result of indirect economic pressures. The ‘economic’ and the
‘political’ therefore appear as distinct, particularised forms of domination in
abstraction from capitalist relations of production. This stance enables one to
understand capitalism as a historical phenomenon and directs analysis towards
an investigation of the internal relationship between the ‘political’ and the ‘economic’.
This includes, for example, an analysis of the role of the state and how, while
appearing separate from the market, the state ensures capitalism through a
guarantee of the institution of private property.
Alex Callinicos
has separately indicated that the two distinct but related registers of capitalist
accumulation and geopolitical competition need to be integrated into a
contemporary understanding of global capitalism. Thus, in his book Imperialism and
Global Political Economy he considers two logics of power, capitalistic
and territorial, with the geopolitics of the states-system treated as a
dimension of the capitalist mode of production. As we note in our JAPE article,
we see a common problem with the above viewpoints on the geopolitics of
capitalism. First, when discussing global developments, they fall back into a state-centric
(almost neo-realist) discussion of state rivalry, as also noted by Gonzalo
Pozo-Martín in the Cambridge
Review of International Affairs. The internal relation between the ‘economic’
and the ‘political’ is, as a result, not transferred into the analysis. Second,
this state-centric focus also prevents these viewpoints from recognising and
conceptualising recent developments in global capitalism, expressed in the
emergence of transnational production networks and integrated global financial
markets, which have transformed the inter-state system.
Here it is William
Robinson who has established a distinctive position in acknowledging the
emergence of transnational capital and labour as significant new actors as a
result of the transnationalisation of the social relations of production. In
his book Latin
America and Global Capitalism (awarded the 2009 Best Book Prize of the International
Political Economy Group of the British International Studies Association),
and in A
Theory of Global Capitalism, he
argues that not only has transnational capital emerged as a new leading social
force but the task of guaranteeing capitalist accumulation on a global scale also
befalls an emerging transnational state (TNS). At the domestic level, states are
perceived as mere transmission belts, ensuring that the demands of the TNS are
implemented. While we agree with his focus on transnational capital, we
criticise the notion of the TNS on the following two grounds:
- it overlooks that states continue to be significant nodal points in the organisation of capitalist accumulation; and
- it fails to acknowledge the continuing relevance of the unevenness of capitalist development between and within states;
In short,
Robinson incorrectly delinks uneven development from the inter-state system. If
certain Marxist viewpoints remind us of neo-realist state-centrism, then
transnational state thinking falls into the liberal trap of assuming the
retreat of the state.
In order to
conceptualise the internal relationship between the geopolitics of the
states-system and global capitalism we draw on the work of Antonio Gramsci and
Nicos Poulantzas. For Gramsci, the state is understood as the form of a
particular condensation of class forces as well as the terrain within which and
through which these class forces struggle to achieve hegemony. It is then
through the social relations of production that the internal relation between
the ‘political’ and the ‘economic’, state and market, manifest themselves.
Poulantzas
focused on how transnational capital became internalised, particularly within
European forms of state through foreign direct investment, since the 1970s as
part of global processes of restructuring. Capital is not simply represented as
an autonomous force beyond the power of the state but is embodied by classes or
fractions of classes within the very constitution of the state. The phenomenon
now referred to as globalisation therefore represents the transnational
organisation of production relations which are internalised within states to
lead to a modified restructuring (but not retreat) of the state in everyday
life.
New
transnational class forces of capital do not, however, confront the state as an
external actor, as a transnational state, but are closely involved in the class
struggle over hegemonic projects within state forms. The exact way this is
played out through struggles and resistance and the extent to which the interests
of transnational capital become internalised within individual state forms
needs to be empirically assessed. It is likely to be a variegated and
differentiated terrain of struggle, differing from state to state depending on
the diverse configuration of class forces and institutional set-ups at the
national level in line with different historical trajectories of state
formation.
In sum, seen in
this way, globalisation and the related emergence of new transnational forces
of capital and labour has not led to a retreat of the state, a strengthening of
the state, or the emergence of a transnational state. The transnational state
is a will-o’-the-wisp (or jack-o’-lantern, or Min Min light): a delusive or
misleading phenomenon. Instead, focus should be held on the unfolding process
of capitalist restructuring marked by an internalisation within different state
forms of new configurations of class forces expressed by struggles between varied
(national and transnational) fractions of capital and labour.
Adam David Morton is Professor of Political Economy at Sydney University/Australia.
Andreas Bieler is Professor of Political Economy at Nottingham University/UK.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Comments welcome!