The notion of uneven and combined
development has attracted increased academic and activist attention. The
concept of unequal exchange, in turn, has been established for some time. What
has not been analysed is how these sets of capitalist dynamics intersect. In a
new article in the journal Globalizations,
entitled ‘Uneven
and combined development and unequal exchange: the second wind of neoliberal
‘free trade’?’, Adam David Morton and I analyse the way in which current
neoliberal ‘free trade’ policies are related to these fundamental capitalist
dynamics, deepening further processes of uneven and combined development as
well as unequal exchange. We also highlight the implications for labour as a
result of the widening uneven and combined development of neoliberalism.
A general point to start with, following
Rosa Luxemburg, is that capitalism’s outward dynamic seeks to secure new growth
points of accumulation to overcome internal crises. These crises, she argued,
cannot be resolved within capitalism itself but are offset by opening up new
markets elsewhere. In other words, capitalism depends on the constant
possibility of outward expansion into non-capitalist spaces (see also Spaces
of Capital and Rosa Luxemburg).
Further, it was Leon Trotsky who
introduced the notion of uneven and combined development in his book Results and Prospects in 1906, when
analysing the particular location of Russia within the world economy. While
Russia was economically ‘backward’, indicating the unevenness of development in
relation to advanced Western countries, a number of small pockets of highly
developed industries – especially in military-related production, were
established as a result of foreign pressures from more ‘advanced’ West
competitor states. Hence, capitalist expansion is also ‘combined’ as a result of
the external pressures of capitalist development on less developed countries.
In short, in response to the crisis tendencies of capitalism, there is an
inherent dynamic of outward expansion along uneven and combined developmental
processes.
In
more recent times, Samir Amin, director of the Third World Forum, has distinguished
two different periods related to the outward expansion of capital. These
capture two different processes linked to how peripheral spaces have been
repeatedly integrated within global capitalism. Initial efforts to offset the
tendency of the rate of profit to fall have revolved around:
1)
enlarging markets and exploiting new regions where the rate of surplus value
was higher than at the centre; and
2)
reducing the cost of labour power and of constant capital.
The
fresh geographical extension of capitalism’s domain over peripheral spaces is
then established through the mechanism of primitive accumulation. As Amin puts
in his book Unequal Development: An Essay
on the Social Formations of Peripheral Capitalism, published by Monthly Review Press:
‘The
characteristic feature of primitive accumulation, in contrast to normal
expanded reproduction, is unequal exchange, that is, the exchange of products
whose prices of production, in the Marxist sense, are unequal’.
Since the post-1945 age of monopoly
capitalism, expanded reproduction has been secured not simply by integrating
non-capitalist spaces, but through restructuring the way in which peripheral
spaces are integrated within the global political economy. Amin describes this
period as the ‘second wind’ of uneven and combined development. Through the
export of capital, forms of production have been established in peripheral
spaces, enjoying the advantage of low-wage costs. As a result, peripheral
spaces have not only exported primary products from extractive industries or
agriculture, but increasingly also manufactured goods. These goods, however,
are predominately characterised by low, outdated technological inputs and cheap
labour. Hence it is the difference in productivity levels, in which high-valued
added goods produced in the core are exchanged for goods based on more living
labour inputs from the periphery, which is the key to unequal exchange. This
ultimately further deepens the inequalities between ‘core’ and ‘peripheral’
capitalist spaces.
In sum, the continuity and intensification
of different productivity rates between developed and developing countries and,
thereby, unequal exchange, is ensured through the ‘second wind’ of uneven and
combined development.
by Alejandra H. Covarrubias |
By opening up peripheral spaces to high
productivity service corporations, some form of ‘development’ will result but
the question to pose is for whom? as
the old problem of combining elements of ‘advanced’ technological progress with
the lagging effects of older ‘backward’ elements remains. As a result,
processes of uneven and combined development are further extended while
peripheral capitalist spaces become locked into new relationships of unequal
exchange. Peripheral capitalist spaces are yet again transformed in the latest
extension of capitalist relations of production through the ‘second wind’ of
‘free trade’.
In short, ‘free trade’ has always played
an important role in the outward expansion of capitalism. Initially,
non-capitalist spaces provided new markets to absorb surplus goods from centres
of ‘advanced’ capitalism. During the second phase, GATT negotiations
facilitated further trade in manufactured goods. It is, however, the most
recent period, in which the ‘free trade’ agenda has expanded, reaching into
areas of financial investment and service provision, thereby adopting its most
significant role.
This situation heralds perhaps a new,
third period reconstituting the relationships of unequal exchange between
spaces of the global political economy as a result of continuing and
intensified uneven and combined development. It is these dynamics around the
expanded free trade agenda, which Ray Kiely in his book Rethinking
Imperialism refers to as a new phase of neoliberal, free trade imperialism.
The
implications for labour and its potential agency of resistance against further
restructuring are complex. Precisely because capitalist expansion has been
uneven, labour movements in different state spaces find themselves in
contrasting locations within the global political economy. Thus, while some
labour movements may feel that further capitalist expansion is in their
interest and albeit only at first sight, others realise the detrimental impact
the expanded ‘free trade’ agenda implies.
When
Trotsky analysed the way Russia was integrated into the global political
economy through processes of uneven and combined development at the beginning
of the twentieth century, he wanted to understand the structural preconditions
of the Russian situation and in what way it may facilitate revolutionary
upheaval. The element of combined development is crucial in this respect, since
it brings together the most ‘advanced’ social forms with ‘backward’ social
forms, resulting in unstable state spaces, forming an explosive situation. Peripheral
spaces, therefore, are potentially a fertile ground for revolutionary uprisings.
The increasing numbers of labour strikes in China and the collective power of
opposition forces in public spaces such as Tahrir Square in Cairo, Syntagma
Square in Athens and Taksim Square in Istanbul are testimony to such an understanding
of the situation.
Adam David Morton is Professor of Political Economy at Sydney University/Australia.
Andreas Bieler is Professor of Political Economy at Nottingham University/UK.
Adam David Morton is Professor of Political Economy at Sydney University/Australia.
Andreas Bieler is Professor of Political Economy at Nottingham University/UK.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Comments welcome!